In Defence of the Impartiality of Barristers and Door Tenants in ISDS: A Call for Departure from Hrvatska Elektroprivreda d.d. v. Republic of Slovenia

In Defence of the Impartiality of Barristers and Door Tenants in ISDS: A Call for Departure from Hrvatska Elektroprivreda d.d. v. Republic of Slovenia

*Batuhan Betin

To venture so brazenly as to critique an order promulgated by the most distinguished of tribunals, comprised of Jan Paulsson, Charles N. Brower, and David A. R. Williams QC (as he was then), presiding, may be comparable to an act of sacrilege. Alas, heresy is precisely what the tribunal’s Order, dated May 6th, 2008, in Hrvatska Elektroprivreda d.d. v. Republic of Slovenia provokes. In classrooms, misinformed articulations of the case garner polarizing responses from students. It prompts those educated in the institutions of the British Isles (and equally, the Commonwealth) to react viscerally, raising their hands in hopes of being called upon to clarify the particularities of the seemingly alien system of barristers’ chambers—much to the amusement of their contemporaries hailing from “enlightened” civil law jurisdictions who stubbornly refuse to distinguish barristers from the lawyers of their native lands.

Despite its notoriety, the case has attracted limited academic commentary.

At the crux of Hrvatska Elektroprivreda d.d. v. Republic of Slovenia was a list communicated on April 25th, 2008, tabulating the members of the Respondent’s representatives who would be attending the  inaugural arbitral hearing scheduled a fortnight from then (¶ 3). Amongst the constituents of the list was Mr. David Mildon QC (as he was then) (¶ 3). Mr. Mildon KC (as he is now) was, and still is, a barrister operating out of Essex Court Chambers, in London (¶ 3). Mr. Williams KC (as he is now) was, at the time, a “door tenant” operating out of the very same set of chambers (¶ 3). The Claimant’s representatives declared that they had not been aware of Mr. Mildon KC’s retainer before the above-mentioned letter (¶¶ 4-5). They promptly requested disclosure of Mr. Mildon KC’s affiliations with the presiding arbitrator (¶ 5), and subsequently petitioned for Mr. Mildon KC to be removed on grounds that Mr. Williams KC could not ‘be relied upon to “judge fairly”’ (¶ 15).

The tribunal evaluated the interrelationship between Mr. Mildon KC and Mr. Williams KC and found that there was justifiable “apprehension of partiality” (¶ 31).  It ordered that “Mr. David Mildon QC may not participate further as counsel in this case” (Ruling). The Tribunal’s decision to order the removal of Mr. Mildon KC was inspired by a medley of considerations. The seemingly most decisive and foundational consideration was the Tribunal’s finding that there was a justifiable “apprehension of partiality” because “the London Chambers system is wholly foreign to” the Claimant (¶ 31). Admittedly, this was bolstered by the tardy timing of the disclosure of Mr. Mildon KC’s retainer (only two weeks prior to the first hearing). Without reserving a firm position as to whether this case was wrongly decided, this article seeks to challenge the precedential value of this Order vis-à-vis future cases where members of the same chambers are appointed as arbitrators and counsel. Even the most authoritative of arbitral treatises, much (presumably) to their editors’ chagrin, cautiously cite this Order as a persuasive authority that the presence of both members serves as a basis for a serious risk of impropriety (Redfern and Hunter on International Arbitration (7th Edition), ¶ 4.138).

This article seeks to deconstruct two critical features of the Order. First, it shall seek to prove that, in hindsight, the Tribunal applied an erroneous subjective standard in discerning whether there was a risk of an appearance of partiality in contradiction to Article 14(1) of the Convention on the Settlement of Investment Disputes between States and Nationals of Other States. Secondly, it advocates that the Tribunal could have more precisely characterized and investigated the interrelationship between Mr. Mildon KC and Mr. Williams KC. In particular, it seeks to demonstrate that the position of “door tenant” may be distinguished from that of a traditionally tenanted member of chambers. Consequently, the particularities of the former may mandate that in future disputes, tribunals should be cautious when applying principles generally applicable to “inter-barrister” relationships mutatis mutandis to “barrister-door tenant” relationships. To this extent, it seeks to discourage blanket recourse to the present Order.

The Tribunal applied erroneous standards in assessing the appearance of partiality. As previously mentioned, it articulated firstly, and seemingly decisively, that the Claimant had a justifiable “apprehension of partiality” because “the London Chambers system is wholly foreign to” them (¶ 31) (emphasis added). This assessment is problematic in that it endorses a subjective evaluation of the arbitrator’s partiality. It essentially adopts the position articulated by the Claimant’s representatives, that whereas the interrelationship “may not be cause for concern in London . . . [v]iewed from the Claimant’s cultural perspective, such concerns are justified” (¶ 10) (emphasis added). However, the prevailing view amongst ICSID tribunals today is that the independence of an arbitrator must be assessed, objectively, on the basis of “whether a reasonable third party, with knowledge of all the facts, would consider that there were reasonable grounds for doubting that an arbitrator possessed the requisite qualities of independence and impartiality” (Schreuer’s Commentary to the ICSID Convention p.1570 (emphasis added); see also Suez and Vivendi v Argentina ¶ 78; EDF v Argentina ¶¶ 109-111). A negative formulation of the test can also be articulated as follows: “a reasonable and informed third party would find it highly likely that the arbitrator’ lacked independence and impartiality” (p.1591; see also Caratube and Hourani v Kazakhstan ¶ 90). The Tribunal deviates from objectivity in that it assesses partiality exclusively from the subjective eyes of the particular Claimant to the dispute, as opposed to the objective lenses of the reasonable third party.

The Tribunal also failed to consider whether the Claimant could have become familiar with this purportedly ‘wholly foreign’ system through knowledge of all the relevant facts. Indeed, this is perplexing given that the Tribunal unequivocally acknowledged earlier in the Order that “[b]arristers are sole practitioners . . . [t]heir Chambers are not law firms” (¶ 17) (emphasis added). Whereas the Tribunal did caveat this statement by cautioning that “th[e] practice [of barristers] is not universally understood,” (¶ 18) it nonetheless tacitly acknowledged how readily accessible this information was. For instance, it pointed to the website of Essex Court Chambers in which unambiguous wording declared, “Chambers is not a firm, nor are members partners or employees. Rather, Chambers contains the separate, self-contained offices of individual barristers each self-employed and working separately” (¶ 17) (emphasis added).

Nowadays there is even greater transparency regarding this phenomenon. The Bar Council of England and Wales’ 2014 Information Note, and its recent 2022 Brochure, underscore that “barristers practicing from traditional sets of chambers are self-employed and are not [emphasis added] in partnership,” and “[b]arristers in the same chambers are fully independent of each other,” respectively. Similar disclaimers are customarily promulgated on the websites of Chambers. In the increasingly globalized world of arbitration, where the participation of barristers is ever-increasing, there is no sound reason precluding the representatives of opposing parties from explaining the realities of this system to their clients.

The tribunal also sought to caveat its earlier statement on the basis that the practice was not “universally agreed” (¶ 18). This proposition is hardly palatable. The independence of barristers is one of the Ten Core Duties promulgated by the Bar Standards Board (BSB) (the body responsible for the ethical regulation of the profession). It is imbued in various rules codified in the readily and publicly accessible BSB Code of Conduct, which, inter alia, underscores that “[m]embers of chambers are not in partnership but are independent of one another and are not responsible for the conduct of other members” (BSB Handbook v. 4.7, gC131). Even the failure to explain to “unsophisticated lay clients [emphasis added]” that “members of the chamber are, in fact, self-employed individuals who are not responsible for one another’s work,” is itself considered a breach of this Code of Conduct (gC56) (emphasis added). Consequently, any arbitrary attempt to doubt the legitimacy of this inviolable and fundamental principle must be readily rejected by future tribunals.

The Tribunal ought to have more precisely characterized the interrelationship between “door tenants” and barristers.

Even the most widely cited of treatises characterize the present matter as a conflict of interest between two barristers who are members of the same chambers. However, Mr. Williams KC was not a traditional member of Essex Court Chambers, nor did he practice as a litigator therein. In relation to Essex Court Chambers, his capacity was that of a “door tenant” (¶ 3). He appears to have retained his practicing certificate from the Bar of New Zealand where he was a traditional tenant of Bankside Chambers. In the absence of knowledge as to the extent and nature of his relationship with the English set, this article does not, per se, reserve a position as to whether the Tribunal erred in treating Mr. Williams KC akin to a traditional member of chambers. Indeed, as elaborated in detail below, there may be circumstances where such treatment may be justified.

The purpose of this Part is to acknowledge that, and identify why, the Tribunal conflated the roles/capacities of traditional members of chambers and that of their door tenants. It seeks then to dissuade other tribunals from blindly conflating the two, in future disputes, in prospective reliance of the current Order.

The Tribunal’s reluctance to distinguish between traditional members of chambers and door tenants should be attributed to the Background Information section of the 2004 IBA Guidelines on Conflicts of Interest in International Arbitration.  Therein, it is asserted (without much elaboration) that for all relevant intents and purposes, the term “members of chambers” shall, because it is “proper,” include door tenants (pp.456-457). However, the Background Information fails to provide any reason as to why the conflation is necessary or proper.

In practice, the relationship of a door tenant vis-à-vis a traditional member operating out of a set of chambers is not, per se, similar to the latter’s relationship with their contemporaries. One set of construction law barristers distinguishes the former as follows: “A number of individuals who are classed as ‘door tenants’ of Chambers also use the clerking and administrative services of ACL. Door tenants are not members, but the courtesy of displaying their name at the entrance to Chambers has been extended to them” (emphasis added).

Door tenants will likely have other permanent occupations. They may be career academics; they may be “affiliated to, and practice out of, another chamber”; they may even have vocations as lawyers employed full-time in traditional law firms operating out of “foreign” jurisdictions. The roles of a door tenant may also be vastly different vis-à-vis traditional members. Some may perform purely consultative functions. Whereas, admittedly, others will take on casework. One regional set of chambers describes the function of their door tenants as follows: “door tenants . . . are available . . . as advisers and consultants and they take on casework which is particular to their field of expertise.” Evidently, one must not blindly conflate the two. Assessment must be made on a case-by-case basis, having regard to the specific nature and extent of the door tenant’s affiliation. Otherwise, one risks arbitrarily mischaracterizing the probability of partiality.

In finding a justifiable appearance of partiality, the Tribunal placed great emphasis on the basis that the promotional materials disseminated by English chambers created a real sense of partnership and collective association amongst their traditional members (¶¶ 17-18). To this end, the Tribunal opined, it was appropriate to treat barristers, in respect of their perception by litigants, akin to solicitors employed in traditional law firms (¶ 19). However, surely, this litmus test can have a countervailing effect. The proactive efforts by chambers to distinguish between permanent members and door tenants (as exemplified for instance by the abovementioned quote from Atkin Chambers) creates a line of delimitation between the two types of tenants. It distances the latter from the former and conveys an unambiguous message that the character of the latter’s affiliation with chambers is likely to be fundamentally different from that of the former.

This is not to say that a “barrister-door tenant” relationship may never warrant disclosure. For instance, where a career academic (Professor A), who is also a door tenant, receives extensive appointments via chambers, their relationship vis-à-vis an ordinary tenanted member may be more akin to a traditional “barrister-barrister” relationship. There, mutatis mutandis application of principles governing the latter may be entirely warranted. However, it is submitted, that due regard must also be had to the secondary nature of a door tenant’s relationship to chambers. Traditionally, a barrister’s principal, if not exclusive, line of business is his self-employed vocation as a litigator, who operates out of the relevant set of chambers. On the contrary, a door tenant has a principal employer or vocation (which may be their primary source of material income). If the same hypothetical Professor A was instead a “hobby arbitrator,” instructed in less than half a handful of cases per annum, it would surely be less persuasive to treat them as if they were any other tenanted barrister.

The failure to distinguish door tenants from traditional barristers also results in certain perplexing outcomes under the 2014 IBA Guidelines on Conflict of Interests in International Arbitration. Professor A who is a door tenant at Chambers B, but a tenured member of the faculty at University C, would be expected to disclose their relationship with Counsel Y who is a junior tenant at Chambers B (¶ 3.3.2). Nonetheless, they would be exempt from disclosing their relationship with Counsel X who is also a tenured member of the faculty at University C (¶ 4.3.3). In light of Professor A’s financial independence from Counsel Y, it is unclear why the risk of bias in favor of Counsel Y is deemed inherently higher than that vis-à-vis Counsel X. Surely, in this hypothetical, the risk of bias should be greater vis-à-vis Counsel X, as a favorable award could bolster the reputation of the faculty, which may in turn indirectly benefit Professor A.

In the modern age, where information is publicly and readily accessible, no reasonable observer armed with the requisite information pertaining to the ethical regulation of barristers should have a good reason for believing that a door tenant is likely to be partial towards counsel hailing from a shared set of chambers by that connection alone. Hrvatska Elektroprivreda d.d. v. Republic of Slovenia must not be interpreted as promulgating a presumption applicable indiscriminately, and capable of producing dispositive outcomes without consideration of the specificities of each prospective conflict. This case also illustrates the desirability of expanding the 2014 IBA Guidelines on Conflict of Interests in International Arbitration such as to provide greater elucidation as to the susceptibility of door tenants (specifically) towards certain biases, with special attention being held to the secondary nature of their vocational relationship with the set. Future tribunals should and must not rely on the present Order as legitimizing the indiscriminate conflation of the two, potentially vastly different, roles.

Skepticism vis-à-vis the Order has started to emerge outside of the investment arbitration context. In 2012, the London Court of International Arbitration (“LCIA”) Court engaged in perhaps the most “sober” interpretation of the Order. In its Challenge Decision No. LCIA81116 the Court unequivocally found that the mere fact that counsel and arbitrator operate out of the same set of chambers cannot serve as “a [decisive] basis to impose upon him an obligation to disclose the activities of other barristers in his chambers; therefore, non-disclosure of such activities does not give rise to ‘justifiable doubts’” (¶48). It rejected any contention that the collective marketing or promotion of members of chambers could ever usurp this presumption (¶47).  Nonetheless, it cautioned, that the presumption of impartiality amongst barristers is neither inviolable nor irrefutable. On each occasion, it is paramount that one conducts a “fact-based enquiry” into whether that particular relationship, between those two members of the same set of chambers, meets the requisite threshold for an appearance of partiality (¶48). This is a most welcome development. Admittedly, this skepticism may stem from the reality that the LCIA is an inherently English institution. The LCIA Court is constituted predominately of English and common law qualified practitioners (or of those intimately familiar with the English legal system). Nonetheless, the author hopes to see the LCIA Court’s sobering approach proliferate and prevail amongst its more transnational investment arbitration contemporaries.


*Batuhan Betin holds an LL.M from Queen Mary University of London where he graduated first overall in his cohort. He extends his sincerest gratitude to his good friend Ms. María Rosario Tejada for bringing the HILJ-HIALSA Collaboration on International Arbitration to his attention.


Cover image credit

Arbitrating Human Rights of Third Parties to ISDS Cases

Arbitrating Human Rights of Third Parties to ISDS Cases

Sebastian Sauter Odio*

I. Introduction

Investor-state dispute settlement (“ISDS”) is a mechanism for foreign investors to claim alleged damages caused by host states, primarily based on standards set by international investment agreements (“IIA”). The ISDS regime has been mostly analyzed from the perspective of the investor or the state, setting aside third parties affected by the investment projects. Beyond the investor-state relationship international investment law (“IIL”) implies a complex relationship with other stakeholders, thus obliging the reconciliation of commercial interests with social justice and environmental protection—areas related to human rights (“HR”).

HR of local communities, including indigenous peoples, workers, and consumers can be undermined by a foreign investment project, particularly concerning the extractives industry, the energy sector, and other large-scale projects. Forced displacement and material dispossession violate HR of third parties to an ISDS claim, including the right to housing, food, water, sanitation, education, and a healthy environment, as well as cultural human rights (see Bangladesh Accord Arbitrations, Bhopal Gas Case (Union Carbide Corp. v. Union of India), Myanmar Yadana Gas Field (Unocal Corp.), Nike Child Labor, Shell v. Nigeria, Philip Morris v. Uruguay, Philip Morris v. Australia, Lone Pine Inc. v. Canada, Vattenfall v. Germany, Spence v. Costa Rica, Methanex v. USA). More importantly, third parties affected by such projects are often unaware of the ISDS claims that impact their rights and thus unable to exercise such rights, including access to justice and public participation.

Even though third-party rightsholders can bring HR claims to domestic and international courts,  arbitral tribunals have indirectly ruled on HR matters, especially in cases referring to climate change and the environment (see Urbaser v. Argentina, Bear Creek v. Peru, Allard v. BarbadosBurlington Resources v. Ecuador, Cortec Mining v. Kenya, S.D. Myers v. Canada, Perenco v. Ecuador, Biwater v. Tanzania). Thus, in this article, I explore the possibility of arbitrating HR in an ISDS procedure, thus providing third parties directly affected by an investment project with an ADR mechanism currently reserved for foreign investors.

II. A Systematic Approach to IIL

As Jean-Baptiste Racine observes in Arbitrage et droits de l’homme (2021), arbitration, as a creation of contract, is normally associated with business and trading, whilst HR pertain to humanistic, universal, and progressive values.[1] Commonly considered opposite areas of the law in the private-public spectrum, arbitrating a HR dispute may be regarded as incompatible. HR duties are, however, not only assigned to the state but also to private parties. Arbitration itself is a case of a private party making binding decisions between conflicting individuals, a power belonging to the right to justice that is generally reserved to state-court litigation. As such, arbitral tribunals shall comply with the public order and HR related to a private-led dispute resolution mechanism.

On this basis, businesses, including foreign investors, are more aware than ever of the HR implications of their operations and of their corporate social responsibility. They have adopted four main efforts to review substantive and procedural standards of IIAs from a holistic and systematic approach of the law. These efforts include incorporating provisions on sustainable development, environmental, health policy and national security in IIAs.

Firstly, the Business and Human Rights (“BHR”) movement addresses business-related HR abuses based on three main pillars that incorporate the United Nations Guiding Principles on Business and Human Rights (“UNGP”): the state’s duty to respect, protect, and fulfil HR, the role of businesses and their duty to respect HR, and the right to access to remedy of those affected by BHR violations.

Secondly, The Hague Rules on Business and Human Rights Arbitration (“The Hague Rules”) is a soft law instrument based on the UNCITRAL Arbitration Rules and the UNCITRAL Rules on Transparency in Treaty-Based Investor-State Arbitration that attempts to “lower barriers to access to remedy” by establishing procedural rules that respond to the unique nature of the interests involved in BHR disputes.

Moreover, the UNCITRAL Working Group III’s discussions on the reform of ISDS rules have considered a greater role for HR provisions in IIL, including the right to access to justice and its corresponding rights to trial and to due process. UNCTAD’S Work Program on IIAs also addresses the rulemaking of IIA by advising stakeholders to include sustainable development and inclusive growth provisions in IIAs.

Within this framework of increasing consciousness of the interconnectedness of the law, providing access to third-party rightsholders to bring their HR claims to ISDS arbitral tribunals would not only be compliant with recent efforts regarding the normative review of IIAs, but also address power imbalances in ISDS of investors with regards to third parties—especially the privilege of overpassing local state courts.

III.  Addressing ISDS Disparities

ISDS provides investors a dispute settlement mechanism to claim reparations from breaches of IIA standards by host states, including non-compliance of most-favored nation treatment, fair and equitable treatment, and prohibitions to expropriation provisions. Meanwhile, affected third parties, including those whose HR have been violated by foreign investors themselves, must exhaust internal state mechanisms—for example, obtaining a court ruling with the effects of res judicata—prior to resorting to a standing international HR court. ISDS therefore affords foreign investors a privileged dispute resolution mechanism, to such an extent they can “bypass local courts” and directly resort to an international ad-hoc tribunal, whilst affected third parties must follow the cumbersome procedure of first exhausting internal state mechanisms. This restricts their right to access to justice in relation to the ISDS claim filed by the foreign investor.

In this sense, providing access to ISDS to affected HR third parties would not only rebalance the asymmetries this mechanism has in respect to the investor claimant and third-party rightsholders, but also reinforce their right to access to justice, in accordance with SDG Goal 16. Furthermore, the flexibility of arbitration as an ADR mechanism could enhance the parties’ procedural rights. For instance, if the tribunal is seated in the jurisdiction the HR violation took place, the affected party—usually being local communities—, the foreign investor, and local authorities relevant to the claim may have more access to the knowledge and the functioning of social and cultural relations of local communities, or even receive support from local organizations, and thus enjoy more equal access to communication and effective remedy adjusted to the particularities of the affected party’s reality.

That said, HR claims brought to ISDS cases shall at least comply with particular procedural standards, given the nature of HR and according to the recent normative reviews set forth in section II of this article.

IV. HR Arbitration

Provided the nature and the governing principles of universality, interdependence, indivisibility, and equality of HR, IIA must include special provisions for an ISDS to rule on HR. First and most importantly, parties must agree in good faith to an arbitration clause established in the IIA and/or eventually agree on a side-agreement once the dispute arises. As a product of contract, a dispute may be arbitrable only if the parties have reached such an agreement. Given that a HR dispute relates to fundamental rights, special consideration should be given to the will of the investor and the host state to resolve HR disputes through arbitration. In any case, to be arbitrable, the event that gives origin to the HR violation must be caused by the foreign state and relate to its duties set forth in the IIA.

That said, HR claims should be brought before an ISDS tribunal only if its members have specialized knowledge to interpret and rule on HR. Most ISDS cases are filed before the International Centre for the Settlement of Investment Disputes (ICSID), the Permanent Court of Arbitration, the International Chamber of Commerce, the London Court of International Arbitration, and the Stockholm Chamber of Commerce. Filing ISDS cases before unspecialized HR tribunals may result in investment and HR claims being heard separately by different tribunals, thus, fragmenting dispute settlement proceedings. For instance, local activists often file HR claims before national courts or international HR organizations, which are ruled separately from the investment claim.

Concerning transparency and publicity, the IIA shall include provisions that ensure public access to the award, hence, complying with the state’s international HR obligations regarding the respect, protection, and fulfilment of HR. Current efforts to improve the transparency and neutrality of ISDS include: (1) the creation of the Multilateral Investment Court, a permanent court of standing suggested by the E.U.; and, (2) the Mauritius Convention on Transparency, which provides parties to IIA executed prior to April 1st, 2014, to consent on the application of the UNCITRAL Rules on Transparency in Treaty-based Investor-State Arbitration, setting procedural rules for making publicly available information on ISDS. Amici participation (non-party submissions), public hearings, allowance of observers, as well as the publication of the hearing recordings and transcripts, are other aspects that should be taken into account to guarantee the transparency and neutrality of an ISDS HR procedure.

In terms of remedies, ISDS focuses on economic reparations (compensation), whilst HR requires a broader set of reparations beyond compensation. HR requires, for instance, protective measures for the victim, restitution, rehabilitation, satisfaction and guarantees of non-repetition, as well as collective reparations, or even transitional justice.

On the other hand, the absence of precedent and of an appellate body in arbitration may threaten HR awards and the right to appeal of the parties to the claim. Although an arbitral award is final and binding on the parties (res judicata), it does not set a precedent applicable to other cases. This generates difficulty in predicting outcomes, added to the fact that ISDS tribunals have ruled differently on similar IIA provisions. Moreover, the lack of an appellate body also adds difficulty to the predictability and interpretation of the IIA, insofar as the review of awards sets rules on correcting first instance rulings and provides legal certainty.

Furthermore, the enforcement of an HR award will ultimately depend on the local jurisdiction of and the applicable law to the arbitration agreement. Despite awards being practically enforceable worldwide following the 1958 New York Convention (“NYC”), according to Article 1.3, State Parties may use reservations and hence limit the application of the NYC to commercial matters. As long as HR claims are not defined as commercial matters, states are free to exclude HR disputes from the scope of the application of the NYC and therefore reserve HR claims to domestic courts; as such, the enforcement of an HR award is often a matter of politics.

Even when IIAs respond to the matters mentioned above, the absence of precedent and of an appellate court, compounded by issues regarding the enforcement of the award and specialization of the ISDS tribunal, challenge the possibility of arbitrating HR of affected third parties to ISDS claims.

IV. Conclusion

While ISDS was initially created to protect foreign investors against arbitrary state measures, the increasing awareness of businesses of their corporate and social responsibilities, including HR violations caused by foreign investors, have resulted in exploring alternative ways of providing affected third parties with an ADR mechanism that corresponds to the privilege ISDS entails for foreign investors.

Arbitrating HR of local communities, workers, and consumers breached by foreign investors would not only conform to the systematic approach IIL demands and to the efforts on the normative review of IIAs (including UNGP, The Hague Rules, and UNCITRAL Working Group III and UNCTAD’S Work Program’ discussions), but also enhance the state’s international HR duties and the parties’ right to access to justice.

In this regard, arbitrating HR of third parties to ISDS cases can be feasible if (1) the investor and the host states have executed a valid arbitration agreement; (2) the tribunal is specialized in HR; (3) the publicity and/or transparency of the arbitration proceedings are guaranteed; and (4) the awards are enforceable in that they provide appropriate remedies to the claimant. If the arbitration procedure complies with these requirements, arbitral tribunals should be able to rule on HR claims. However, the absence of precedent and of an appellate tribunal remain tangible challenges to arbitrating HR of third parties to ISDS cases.


*Sebastian Sauter Odio is a Costa Rican associate attorney and editor-in-chief of the Costa Rican Journal of International Law. In 2022 he obtained his Licenciatura en Derecho (J.D. equivalent) with honors from the University of Costa Rica. He has special interests in Private and Public International Law, Human Rights, politics, and environmental matters.

[1] Jean-Baptiste Racine, Lecture presented at The Hague Academy of International Law Online Summer Course on Private International Law on “Arbitrage et Droits de L’Homme” (2021).


Cover image credit 

Navigating the International Investment Maze: Dissecting Imbalances, Ditching BITs, and Charting a Course Towards Sustainable Solutions

Navigating the International Investment Maze: Dissecting Imbalances, Ditching BITs, and Charting a Course Towards Sustainable Solutions

Abdelhameed Dairy*

Introduction

The paper critically assesses the contemporary challenges facing the international investment regime, concluding that urgent reform is needed. It argues for abandoning Bilateral Investment Treaties (“BITs”) as the prevailing tools. The first part of this article characterizes the regime as an “imbalanced bargain” and highlights the regime’s inability to achieve objectives, leading to regulatory chill and hindering sustainable development goals. The second and third parts of the article propose a novel reform approach centered on the doctrine of acquired rights within a domestic legal framework, offering a comprehensive solution to existing challenges. The researcher advocates for terminating BITs, emphasizing the need for transformative legal adjustments to address the regime’s shortcomings. The methodological approach aligns with Sauvant’s emphasis on understanding the regime’s purpose as a foundation for meaningful reform discussions.

I. Background and Objectives

The global response to enhancing protection for foreign investors, framed as a “Grand Bargain,” has been subject to critical examination (Kaushal 2009; Salacuse and Sullivan 2005). Asha Kaushal revisits the history of the foreign investment regime to illuminate the present backlash against the regime, shedding light on its historical underpinnings. Kaushal’s findings underscore the tensions inherent in the BIT architecture, revealing a disconnect between the intended benefits of BITs and their actual impact on foreign investment flows (Kaushal 2009, p. 492-496).  While these treaties were originally envisioned as a means to attract investment by trading regulatory sovereignty, recent studies suggest that they may not significantly influence investment patterns. Moreover, Kaushal argues that the real bargain underlying BITs involves developing countries relinquishing sovereignty in exchange for enhanced protection of foreign property and contract rights (Kaushal 2009, p. 495).  This nuanced understanding of the BIT regime challenges traditional binary structures and highlights internal contradictions within the investment arbitration framework. Jeswald Salacuse and Nicholas Sullivan, in their evaluation of bilateral investment treaties, question the efficacy of the grand bargain inherent in these treaties (Salacuse and Sullivan 2005, p.77). The perceived imbalance in this arrangement stems from three key factors: states’ choice to enter into investment treaties in a “blind bargain” without full certainty as to their effects, provision of ‘more than just” protection for investments, and restrictions on the State’s right to regulate.

A. A Blind Bargain: A Historical Perspective

The historical evolution of international investment law, rooted in the assumption that BITs would spur economic development through increased foreign direct investments, is increasingly questionable (Kenneth Vandevelde 2009, p.21; Hallward-Driemeier 2003). The lack of empirical evidence supporting this assumption (Dolzer and Schreuer 2012, p. 23; Salacuse and Sullivan 2005, p.17) transforms entering the commitment to BITs into a speculative gamble. The early 1990s marked a shift toward neoliberal economic policies and the establishment of BITs, guided by the belief that they would foster economic development (UNCTAD 2006, p. 2, 6).

However, the paper contends that this anticipated correlation between BITs and economic development lacks empirical support. Hence, it characterizes the treaties as “blind bargains”. The paper also aligns with the view that while investment protection is an important objective, its direct translation to promotion and liberalization is not always guaranteed (UNCTAD 2003, p. 89).

B. More than Extra Protection

The surge in costly arbitration claims against host states, exceeding initial expectations, forms the second facet of the imbalanced bargain. This rise in claims, attributable to the expansive scope of BITs and their broad definitions of investments—such as in Joy Mining v Egypt (para. 45)—prompts a critical examination. Significantly, the origins of BITs are also implicated, with some arguing (Miles 2010) that the focus on investors’ interests may have led to the neglect of the host state’s interests. The unique privilege granted to foreign investors to initiate legal proceedings against host states is explored, emphasizing the need to redefine investments for better precision.

Upon revisiting the shared objectives of the regime and exploring its history, it is apparent that BITs were embraced with a specific goal: advancing the economic development of host states. This distinguishes BITs from human rights conventions. BITs focus on safeguarding investors’ property (Dolzer and Schreuer 2012, p. 60). The deliberate choice of developing countries to limit BITs to future investments highlights their core aim of promoting future Foreign Direct Investment (“FDI”), which contributes significantly to economic development Salacuse and Sullivan 2005, p. 80). Unfortunately, the lack of a precise objective definition in BITs’ preambles often leads to the inadvertent inclusion of potentially detrimental investments (UNCTAD 2011, pp. 1-13). This drafting oversight may stem from the novelty of this legal field, as acknowledged in the ICSID Convention (Mihaly International Corp. v. Democratic Socialist Republic of Sri Lanka, para. 33).

As we consider the focus of the next chapter of investment protection, a crucial question arises: is the optimal avenue for developing investment law through BITs or domestic law? Host states have, over time, attempted a political approach to rebalance the “bargain” by modifying definitions in BITs (Kenneth Vandevelde 2009, pp. 186-187). Arbitral tribunals, adopting a legal approach, refine their interpretation of “investment”. This approach is exemplified in the Fedax v. Venezuela case which employs a “criteria approach” to define investments and establish prerequisites for protected investments. The Salini v. Morocco case, known for creating the “Salini Test”, sets criteria for an investment’s eligibility. However, a recent divergence of opinion among tribunals, particularly regarding the development clause, indicates ongoing debate. (Victor Pey Casado and President Allende Foundation v. Republic of Chile, L.E.S.I. S.p.A. and ASTALDI S.p.A. v. République Algérienne Démocratique et Populaire; Inmaris Perestroika Sailing Maritime Services GmbH and Others v. Ukraine). The development clause, often included in investment agreements and BITs, aims to ensure that foreign investment is not protected unless it contributes positively to the economic, social, and environmental development of the host country.

In summary, host states, aiming to foster economic development, have provided additional protection for foreign investments through BITs. Despite efforts to rebalance the “bargain”, harmful investments still receive extensive protection, challenging sustainable development goals. To address this, a proposed solution involves establishing a “sustainable foreign direct investment definition” which excludes detrimental investments from BIT protection. Our proposal of domestic law solutions—explored later—offers a more effective mechanism for excluding harmful investments.

C. The State’s Right to Regulate

The third element of the “imbalanced bargain” focuses on the constriction of the state’s right to regulate by BITs. While protecting foreign investors from unfair measures is acknowledged, our suggestion delves into the challenge of distinguishing between opportunistic and bona fide regulatory measures. The legitimacy crisis surrounding the regime, and particularly the threat of regulatory chill, is discussed. These concerns arise from the difficulty in balancing the protection of foreign investors with the state’s regulatory autonomy, leading to potential reluctance in enacting or enforcing regulations perceived as necessary for public welfare.

This paper advocates for the termination of BITs, emphasizing that they have failed in achieving their objectives. The imminent termination of BITs is evidenced by states initiating the process in response to the prevailing legitimacy crisis. This proposal advocates a shift from international to domestic law, offering a pragmatic solution to core issues, and preserving international arbitration but introducing a doctrinal gateway for consistency.

II. The Doctrine of Acquired Rights

Our proposal advocating domestic law as an alternative to BITs is based on the doctrine of acquired rights. The concept of acquired rights is a legal principle that protects rights which have already been acquired or established by individuals or entities under the law. It is a pivotal element within our suggested domestic investment law.

A. International Doctrinal Confirmation

Anticipating criticism about the shift from international (BITs) to national (domestic law), we address the key question of state succession’s impact on “acquired rights”. Affirmed by international tribunals, this principle, rooted in public international and municipal law, gained legitimacy in the landmark Saudi Arabia and Aramco case (see also Golâenberq; Permanent Court of International Justice). The doctrine of acquired rights was historically controversial because newly independent Global South states perceived it to threaten their sovereignty. However, this controversy largely evaporated in the early 1990s as developing and developed countries came into agreement over the importance of  Hence, I argue for a revival of the acquired rights doctrine. Apart from the historical controversies on the application of this doctrine in the international sphere and considering that in our proposal the disputes between host states and investors shall be settled through international arbitrators, the international formal recognition of the doctrine is attached to its importance in the field of investment law and confers upon its legitimacy in content and principle.

B. The Content of the Doctrine

The doctrine of acquired rights typically prevents governments or other parties from retroactively changing laws or regulations in a way that would deprive individuals or entities of rights they have already obtained. Initially, the doctrine was a safeguard against state interference with property rights, and has international recognition. Our proposed National Foreign Investment Law (“NFIL”) safeguards FDIs against post-investment regulatory changes. The scope of acquired rights within the NFIL is limited to rights explicitly acquired through it. We propose a definition encompassing tangible and intangible rights, aligned with NFIL standards. As compared to stabilization clauses, NFILs better ensure alignment with host state constitutional principles.

C. Acquired Rights and Sustainable Development in National Foreign Investment Law (“NFIL”)

In our proposed NFIL, the concept of “right” within “acquired rights” is pivotal. Valid legal rules establishing rights would seamlessly align with sustainable development goals due to the hierarchy of norms. The NFIL, being more adaptable than BITs, would be crafted to appeal to non-governmental organizations (NGOs) by incorporating constitutional principles. To exemplify, if principles like environmental protection are embedded in the host state’s constitution, any investor rights conflicting with these principles would be null and unconstitutional. This aligns investor interests with the host state’s constitutional values, increasing predictability for investors and fostering sustainable and responsible FDIs. As a result, the proposed regime aims to contribute to sustainable development goals by advocating for sustainable FDI rather than merely more FDI. Moreover, it has been noted that it is more beneficial for investors to conduct economic policies that reconcile with their stakeholders’ interests and hence avoid criticism of societies and NGOs.

In defining “acquired” within “acquired rights”, the distinction between pre-establishment and post-establishment rights is crucial. Our proposal addresses concerns around pre-establishment rights. We suggest that NFIL should refrain from granting such rights. Host states not obligated to admit foreign investments (Droit international économique. Dalloz 2003, pp. 361-365), gain more control over FDI inflow without compromising fairness. The absence of pre-establishment rights in NFIL avoids an overly liberalizing perception and allows states to tailor liberalization levels to their policy stances.

D. Stabilization Clauses and the Doctrine of Acquired Rights

Our proposal centers on activating the doctrine of acquired rights in the NFIL, akin to stabilization clauses but with notable distinctions. Stabilization clauses, often criticized for hindering sustainable development, freeze a broad scope of regulations (and sometimes freeze the whole legal framework) at the time of the investment. In contrast, our concept of acquired rights focuses on freezing specific regulations and offers more precise control. The proposed “right” concept, mandating alignment with constitutional principles, echoes suggested remedies for stabilization clause shortcomings related to environmental and social considerations.

In essence, our NFIL approach strikes a balance: it promotes sustainable FDI by aligning investor rights with host state values, avoids broad pre-establishment rights, and offers a nuanced alternative to stabilization clauses.

III. Domestic Law as an Alternative and a Solution

Following the examination in Part I, this Part questions the relevance of BITs and explores domestic law as an alternative. It proposes two remedies for investor disputes: an Investor-State Dispute Settlement (“ISDS”) clause within the NFIL and the theory of acquired rights. Domestic law, viewed through the lens of other legal frameworks like labor law, offers a stable source for managing host state-investor relationships. The chapter underscores the equivalence of domestic law to BITs’ goals and its effectiveness as a superior instrument.

A. Investor Remedies in Domestic Law

Our suggestion of a NFIL proposes incorporating an ISDS clause into the NFIL and utilizing the theory of acquired rights. It contends that domestic law can offer a stable legal framework, addressing investor concerns and facilitating long-term relationships between investors and host states. The next section challenges the notion that domestic law lacks stability and emphasizes the importance of aligning investor interests with host state constitutional principles.

B. Serving the Same Objectives

Comparing domestic law to BITs, our proposed NFIL represents a credible legal framework, providing stability, predictability, and precise obligations. The NFIL with ISDS clauses contributes to investment liberalization by supplanting the Most Favored Nation (“MFN”) treatment (in principle) with a standardized legal framework. The NFIL, characterized by its legal structure comprising general and abstract rules, encompasses all foreign investors within a unified legal framework. Consequently, it supplants the MFN standard of protection by incorporating all foreign investors falling under the definition of investment in the relevant NFIL, irrespective of the BITs their home country has established with the host state.

In the pursuit of a solution to balance investor protection and regulatory flexibility, the next section focuses on the role of domestic law. Our approach suggests a distinction between investors’ rights and privileges while maintaining the state’s right to regulate.

C. The State’s Right to Regulate

The suggested NFIL would offer a framework to differentiate between compensable and non-compensable measures. A NFIL should define investors’ rights and privileges at the time of investment, ensuring that acquired rights remain unchanged, while privileges, such as the renewal application for operating a hazardous waste landfill, may be subject to legitimate regulatory changes.

Regarding general regulatory measures, the NFIL allows states to enact measures for public interest reasons without arbitration concerns provided they do not infringe on acquired rights. This grants host states the flexibility to adjust policies for future investors without being bound by previous investors’ rights.

Privileges obtained by investors can be modified for public interest, yet opportunistic changes may lead to compensation claims. The NFIL’s meticulous drafting is essential to clearly define the scope of acquired rights, minimizing potential debates.

D. Achieving a Multilateral Agreement on Investment (“MAI”)

Our proposed NFIL serves as a potential solution for achieving a MAI by fostering consensus on standards of protection. By allowing states to freely compete within their domestic laws, regulatory competition emerges. This competition encourages jurisdictions to attract FDI by adopting protective frameworks in their NFIL.

The concept of “regulatory competition” within domestic law enables states to compete for FDI with shared objectives, such as protecting, attracting, and liberalizing investment. Countries could compete to attract FDIs by incorporating an extensive Fair and Equitable Treatment standard of protection in their NFIL. This form of competition through domestic law has been witnessed previously, such as in tax law competitions enacting lower minimum wages for employees compared to other countries,  or enhancing flexibility in the labor market.

Some may argue that this competition results in a “race to the bottom” on environmental standards. However, as well as a “Delaware effect”—a race to the bottom with regard to lax restrictions—competition might alternatively result in a “California effect” —a race to the top with regard to restrictions on corporations.

Eventually, regulatory competition will reveal which tools work better to achieve the common objectives, as with different approaches competing through the NIFL, some will witness failure and others will witness success in attracting investment.  As a result, states with approaches that have failed will tend to duplicate the approaches that have succeeded until we attain a consensus on at least fundamental substantive content, and hence regulatory competition will pave the way to attain a MAI on the substantive level.

In summary, the proposed domestic law approach offers a balanced mechanism, allowing states to regulate for the public interest while maintaining a competitive environment for attracting FDI. This perspective aligns with the principles of regulatory competition and has the potential to pave the way for a multilateral consensus on investment standards.

Conclusion

The international investment law framework, aimed at promoting FDI and ensuring its protection, faces a crisis due to insufficient empirical support, unintended extra protection through BITs, and concerns about encroachment on host states’ regulatory rights.

In light of these challenges, terminating BITs is essential.  Domestic law is a superior tool. Domestic law can achieve common goals, remove constraints on regulatory capacity, and align with global sustainable development objectives. It also serves as a crucial step towards a multinational investment agreement, providing a standardized legal framework for international investment law.

*Abdelhameed Dairy is a seasoned legal professional with expertise in case management, legal research, and client relations.

Cover image credit 

To Carve or not to Carve: India’s Investment Treaties Must Look Beyond GATT-Inspired Environmental Carve-Outs to Avoid Regulatory Chill

To Carve or not to Carve: India’s Investment Treaties Must Look Beyond GATT-Inspired Environmental Carve-Outs to Avoid Regulatory Chill

Arijit Sanyal* and Eshan A. Chaturvedi**

Introduction

Environmental and international investment law was a tale of two cities until the onset of climate change. However, the overlaps have visibly increased and conflicted ever since states and international organizations began to address climate change through reforms such as the Paris Agreement and the E.U.’s Green Deal. Notwithstanding the adoption of environmental reforms, implementation has not been smooth due to resistance from investors claiming to be affected by environmental reforms. This resistance has resulted in a rise of Investor-State Dispute Settlement (“ISDS”) claims against states, leading to regulatory chill (¶ 50). Among other measures to limit such claims, states have inserted environmental carve-outs (“carve-outs”) into their respective treaties, inspired by Article XX of the General Agreement on Tariff and Trade (“GATT”), which immunize certain environmental reforms from challenge.

However, GATT-inspired carve-outs have not been effective because ISDS tribunals have continued to hold states responsible for violation of treaty provisions and award compensation to investors—as in Infinito Gold v. Costa Rica and Eco Oro v. Colombia. The ineffectiveness of carve-outs may lead to concerns for countries like India, whose model bilateral investment treaties and free trade agreement investment chapters (“Investment Instruments”) contain similarly worded provisions. Further, India has been engaged in negotiating several new Investment Instruments. However, these developments come when India has undergone several environmental mishaps in the last few years alone.

Thus, the Government of India may contemplate stricter environmental reforms which could encroach upon investments in the energy sector. Against this backdrop, this article discusses why GATT-inspired carve-outs contained in Investment Instruments may no longer be viable. Further, the article proposes a model of carve-out based on Environmental Impact Assessments (“EIA”) which excludes certain claims from the scope of ISDS and makes provision for them to be referred to an alternative mechanism within the framework of the concerned Investment Instrument.

I. Lost Opportunities for GATT-Inspired Carve-Outs

GATT-inspired carve-outs have been put to test in Infinitio Gold and Eco Oro, where claims were initiated for breaches of the Fair and Equitable Treatment (“FET”) standard and other treaty commitments due to environmental measures adopted by Colombia and Costa Rica. Despite attempts by Colombia and Costa Rica, the tribunals did not preclude compensation and stated that the carve-out could not be allowed to operate in a way that overrides treaty provisions dealing with FET.

The carve-out contained under Article 2201(3) of the Canada-Colombia Free Trade Agreement (“Canada-Colombia FTA”) provides that:

 “. . . [N]othing in this Agreement shall be construed to prevent a Party from adopting or enforcing any measure necessary: a) to protect human, animal or plant life…include environmental measures necessary to protect human, animal or plant life and health . . .” (emphasis added).

In Eco Oro, Colombia argued that Article 2201(3) of the Canada-Colombia FTA was meant to exclude measures adopted to address environmental concerns. Colombia therefore urged the tribunal to not grant compensation for measures covered by Article 2201(3). However, the Tribunal observed that the text of Article 2201(3) of the Canada-Colombia FTA did not preclude the payment of compensation for violation of treaty provisions (¶ 367). The Tribunal further observed that if the parties intended to exclude any liability from their actions, the provisions of the respective treaties should have been drafted to reflect this intent (¶¶ 368-369). Consequently, the Eco Oro tribunal concluded that Article 2201(3) was meant to shield environmental measures and that the investors could not ask for restitution. But the provision’s ordinary meaning did not preclude the award of compensation when environmental measures violated FET standards.

This view aligns with that expressed by the Infinitio Gold tribunal, which found that whilst Annex 1, Section III(1) of the Canada-Costa Rica Free Trade Agreement affirmed a state’s right to regulate, it could not be understood to override substantive treaty provisions. Further, the Infinitio Gold tribunal affirmed that exceptions had to be interpreted to balance investor and environmental protection. The abovementioned interpretations indicate that GATT-inspired carve-outs have not been interpreted to exclude compensation for breach of treaty provisions. On the contrary, the abovementioned awards may have created an impression that GATT-inspired carve-outs are meant to bail out states for breach of treaty provisions, whereas the provisions’ real purpose is to exclude certain actions from the scope of ISDS.

II. Have Carve-Outs Hit a Dead-End?

Eco Oro and Infinitio Gold indicate that GATT-inspired carve-outs may not be the most effective way to exclude environmental measures from being targeted by ISDS claims. Moreover, these tribunals have blurred the lines between the defense of necessity and GATT-style carve-outs which are meant to exist on different planes. While necessity as a defense is deployed after a breach has been found, a carve-out[1] aims at excluding ex ante certain actions from substantive treaty provisions. However, the aforementioned interpretation of GATT-inspired carve-outs in Infinitio Gold and Eco Oro has raised concerns about the suitability of carve-outs in new-generation treaties altogether.

Infinitio Gold and Eco Oro alone should not indicate that carve-outs as tools for safeguarding the state’s capacity to protect the environment have hit a dead-end. Rather, they serve to illustrate that GATT-inspired carve-outs such as those contained in Article 5.4 of the Model India Bilateral Investment Treaty (“India Model BIT”) and Article 6.4 of the Investment Cooperation and Facilitation Treaty between Brazil and India (“Brazil-India BIT”) may not be the best way to protect the policy space required for effective environmental reforms. Further, at the time of writing this article, India was negotiating Investment Instruments without much clarity on environment-related provisions therein. Against this backdrop, it may not be practical for the parties involved to continue with GATT-inspired carve-outs.

Considering the emphasis laid by the Infinitio Gold and Eco Oro tribunals on balancing environmental and investor rights, treaty parties should reorient their approach towards carve-outs. In this regard, they should consider carve-outs that exclude environmental measures from the scope of potential ISDS claims and allow investors to present such claims before a separate mechanism within the framework of the respective Investment Instruments.

III. India’s Investment Instruments

At the time of writing this post, India has been negotiating Investment Instruments with the European Union (“E.U.”), United Kingdom (“U.K.”), Sri Lanka, and other countries. Other Investment Instruments have recently been concluded with Brazil, Kyrgyzstan, and Japan. However, these treaties do not contain uniform and effective environmental protection provisions or carve-outs. For Instance, Article 5.4 of the India Model BIT and Article 6.4 of the Brazil-India BIT provide that non-discriminatory measures taken to protect the public interest and further objectives such as protection of environment protection shall not amount to expropriation.

Though differently worded than Article 2201(3) of the Canada-Colombia BIT, Article 5.4 of the India Model BIT and Article 6.4 of the Brazil-India BIT are inspired by Article XX of the GATT. Consequently, they leave room for arbitral tribunals to determine if a measure was non-discriminatory. For instance, Article 6.4 of Brazil-India BIT provides:

Non-discriminatory regulatory measures by a Party or measures or awards by judicial bodies of a Party that are designated and applied to protect legitimate public interest or public purpose objectives such as public health, safety, and the environment shall not constitute expropriation under this Article” (emphasis added).

Similarly, Article 5.4, India Model BIT provides:

“. . . [N]on-discriminatory regulatory actions by a Party that are designed and applied to protect legitimate public welfare objectives such as public health, safety, and the environment shall not constitute expropriation” (emphasis added).

Though the two abovementioned provisions are similarly worded, Article 6.4 of the Brazil-India BIT has a broader scope and includes pronouncements of judicial bodies in the host states. This may be a cause of greater concern in India, as the higher judicial bodies have usually taken cognizance of environmental and public health-related issues. This increases the possibility of claims by investors in the event that a judicial pronouncement encroaches upon certain investments. Further, there being no express exclusion of liability, along the lines of what was expressed by the Eco Oro tribunal, such claims (if initiated) are likely to be decided in the favor of the investor.

Further, with tribunals having the power to determine if a measure is non-discriminatory, awards have the potential to restrain judicial, administrative, or legislative measures that impact public policies directed towards the environment (p. 344-45). For instance, many tribunals have adopted broad views in interpreting what actions violate non-discriminatory standards, and have even drawn parallels with different sectors to determine if non-discriminatory standards were violated.[2] In this regard, the tribunal in Occidental Exploration and Production v. Republic of Ecuador observed that while determining if a treatment was non-discriminatory, the analysis could not be limited to the circumstances in one exclusive sector. Thus, even if the government of India implements environmental reforms, it cannot be said that such reforms will be immune from the scrutiny of an ISDS tribunal, as the tribunal may end up drawing parallels between what is discriminatory in the environmental sector with discriminatory actions in other sectors have different thresholds.

Another possible concern with the carve-outs under Article 5.4 of the Model India BIT and Article 6.4 of the Brazil-India BIT is that an ISDS tribunal constituted thereunder will not necessarily be bound by domestic law.[3] Hence, measures taken in furtherance of new or existing domestic environmental legislation may be of little relevance to the tribunal. An overview of the awards discussed above and the subjective nature of investment protection norms demonstrate that their interpretation is largely left to ISDS tribunals, who end up interpreting them inconsistently.[4] In this regard, the risk of facing ISDS claims, and the possibility of having to pay the pecuniary obligations of the award, has the potential to prevent India from implementing ambitious environmental reforms and force it to join a long list of other states who have faced a similar fate.[5] Consequently, GATT-inspired carve-outs may not be the most effective way to deal with possible environmental claims at a time when India plans to roll out environmental reforms.

IV. EIA Carve-Outs

Considering the apprehensions of “regulatory chill”, Indian policymakers should consider broadly worded and strategic carve-outs which exclude certain claims from the ISDS mechanism and provide an alternative forum for a certain class of claims within the treaty framework. In this regard, India may consider adopting a broadly worded carve-out, which excludes certain claims from the scope of ISDS, and directs such claims to an alternative forum within the framework of the Investment Instruments. To promote inter-party collaboration in respect of environmental reforms, the proposed mechanism should consist of representatives nominated by state parties to the respective treaties. Such representatives shall be tasked with the examination of claims concerning environmental measures excluded from the traditional ISDS mechanism.

A possible way to achieve the abovementioned mechanism is by adopting an EIA-based carve-out. This approach balances the interests of states and investors. EIAs have primarily been used for screening investments to assess the potential impact of planned investments in the host state’s territory. However, ex-post EIAs can be deployed for assessing the ongoing impact of investments on the environment. This can aid the mechanism in its assessment of an investor’s claims based on scientific parameters. Additionally, the mechanism could allow claims from host states against certain investments, should the EIAs demonstrate adverse effects on the environment of the host state.

V. The Road Ahead

While the utility of EIA carve-outs can be determined once they are put to the test, their balanced approach makes them more likely to succeed than GATT-inspired carve-outs. First, EIA carve-outs can be brought to life by modifying existing Investment Instruments of India which have a relatively higher focus on environmental protection. For instance, the Comprehensive Economic Partnership Agreement between the Republic of India and Japan (“India-Japan CEPA”) could serve as a basis for the proposed carve-out. Article 8(1) of the India-Japan CEPA acknowledges the right of each state party to establish and regulate environmental policies domestically. Further, Article 99 provides that state parties shall not waive environmental measures for the promotion of investments.

The abovementioned provisions are broad enough to serve as a basis for further amendments to include EIA carve-outs. In this regard, the stakeholders may consider including the requirement for furnishing EIAs by investors. One of the possible ways to implement this can be to impose requirements mirroring environmental obligations contained under Articles 8(1) and 99 of the India-Japan CEPA. Consequentially, the envisioned provision would require state parties to consider EIAs by investors, to assess the viability of certain investments within their territory. Alternatively, EIAs could be mandated under the local environmental protection legislations, which will have to be complied with at the time of investing, and throughout the duration of the investment.

Further, stakeholders should deliberate on the structure of the proposed alternative forum. To ensure fairness and transparency, they may consider having representatives of all the state parties as adjudicators of the proposed forum. Eventually, when a claim captured by the carveout arises, the Investment Instrument shall require the aggrieved party to refer the claim to the proposed forum. Considering the nature of environmental reforms, it may also be of interest to the Government of India to negotiate a two-way mechanism with regard to the proposed forum. Given the involvement of EIAs, the Investment Instrument can provide for host states to refer infringement proceedings against investors before the proposed forum.

The proposed provision would impose greater environmental obligations on investors by requiring them to furnish EIAs concerning their investments. Additionally, should investors have concerns about certain environmental measures, their claims will be referred to the proposed forum. Further, the provision should allow host states to bring claims before the proposed forum based on the EIAs submitted by the investors themselves. Thus, apart from furthering the agenda of climate change, the EIA carve-outs will serve as an additional layer to further intra-governmental cooperation in the field of climate change, a step recently suggested under Recommendation 4 of the Draft Legislative Guide on Investment Dispute Prevention and Mitigation.[6]

Conclusion

Eco Oro and Infinitio Gold have demonstrated why GATT-inspired carve-outs may not be the ideal way to shield India from possible ISDS claims based on its environmental policies. Considering the recent environmental mishaps in India, it is likely that stricter environmental reforms are on the horizon. However, considering that India is negotiating several Investment Instruments at the same time, it may be the right opportunity to put such a provision to test and spearhead the ISDS reform movement in light of climate change.

The proposed carve-out reflects the desired balance required to address environmental issues, as it allows the involvement of all stakeholders under an Investment Instrument (states and investors) equally in the adjudicatory process. The involvement of state representatives in the proposed forum may raise concerns regarding the fairness of the entire process. However, this proposal must be understood in light of climate change—which requires states to meet various obligations to safeguard climate concerns. The success of the proposed mechanism can only be known if becomes a reality. However, given the balanced approach of the carve-outs, this approach has the potential to set the right tone for environmental reforms within ISDS in the global south and inspire similar reforms at a time when some countries have entered a state of regulatory chill.


*Arijit Sanyal is an Associate at Skywards Law, New Delhi with the International Disputes & Litigation Team, and a lawyer qualified to practice in New Delhi. Arijit has acted for clients before the Supreme Court of India, High Court of Delhi and Gujarat, and arbitrations administered on an ad-hoc basis and by the ICC, LMAA, SIAC etc. Besides work, Arijit is a Core Team Member of the Moot Alumni Association of the Vis Moot. Arijit has studied arbitration law at the Arbitration Academy in Paris where his essay on climate change and investment arbitration was awarded the “Laureate of the Academy” prize.
**Eshan A. Chaturvedi is an Associate at Skywards Law with the International Disputes & Litigation Team, and a lawyer qualified to practice in New Delhi. Eshan has acted for clients in a series of domestic and international disputes seated in India as well as the U.K., Singapore and MENA under the ICC and SIAC Rules. Eshan has been involved in advising investors and businesses planning to set up an entity in India. Eshan has studied international law at the Hague Academy for Private International Law.
[1] Aarushi Gupta, Eco Oro v. Columbia: Is GATT Article XX to be Blamed?, 89 Int. J. Arb, Mediation & Disp. Mgmt. 21, 27-28 (2023).
[2] Lu Wang, Non-Discrimination Treatment of State-Owned Enterprise Investors in International Investment Agreements, 31 ICSID Rev. – Foreign Inv. L.J. 45, 54.

[3] U.N. Secretary-General, Paying Polluters: The Catastrophic Consequences of Investor-State Dispute Settlement for Climate and Environment Action and Human Rights, ¶ 33, U.N. Doc. A/78/168 (2023) [Paying Polluters].

[4] Wang, supra note 2.

[5] Paying Polluters, supra note 3 at ¶ 50.

[6] U.N. Commission on International Trade Law, Working Group III, Draft Legislative Guide on Investment Dispute Prevention and Mitigation, U.N. Doc. A/CN.9/WG.III/W.P.228 (2023).


 

The Graduate: The E.U. and its Member States’ Exit from the Energy Charter Treaty

The Graduate: The E.U. and its Member States’ Exit from the Energy Charter Treaty

Marios Tokas*

I. Introduction

At the end of ‘Τhe Graduate,’ the protagonist duo happily sits in the back of the bus together. As the music plays on, the duo starts becoming less and less happy as they think about their future and the repercussions of their actions, since Elaine has just fled her wedding to run out with Benjamin to an uncertain future.

The ending scene of ‘The Graduate’ resembles the situation in the aftermath of the denunciation of the Energy Charter Treaty (ECT) by various E.U. member states (including France, Germany and the Netherlands) and the proposal for a so-called coordinated exit together with the E.U. This move radically differs from the E.U.’s previous stance. The E.U.’s previous position, based on a 2022 agreement in principle, favored the adoption of a ‘modernized’ version of the ECT which purported to reduce the protective scope for ‘climate-dirty’ investors.

The coordinated exit will entail two parts: 1) denunciation of the ECT by the E.U., as a member of the ECT, and of the E.U. member states; and 2) an inter se agreement between the E.U. and its member states intended to terminate the 20-year sunset clause in the ECT concerning existing covered investments.

This move has been met with enthusiasm by climate think-tanks which have been advocating for an exit from the ECT for quite some time, calling the ECT a ‘climate-wrecking treaty.’ However, this enthusiasm has gradually faded as disputes continue to arise, politicians with anti-climate agendas are elected, and many states exploit the climate emergency to pursue a protectionist agenda which includes export controls, restrictions in critical raw materials trade, and nationalizations of investments.

Without getting into the debate over the impact of the ECT on the E.U.’s climate goals and the climate policies of the E.U. member states, it is useful to examine what happens next. No politically viable legal instrument is available to replace the ECT at the moment. Meanwhile, the old ECT remains relevant due to its 20-year sunset clause (Article 47.3 ECT), which extends protection to covered investors and investments for 20 years after a party’s denunciation of the ECT. Any investment made before the end of the withdrawal notification’s one-year notice period is also protected under the sunset clause.

In the present article, I provide some reflections on the legal and policy considerations of the uncertain future of investment arbitration in the E.U. in light of the ECT’s apparent collapse.

II. Reasons for the Coordinated Exit

The first argument in favor of the coordinated exit is that it will ensure legal security and predictability within the E.U. and boost climate change cooperation among the E.U. member states. This argument is premised on the fact that many E.U. member states’ energy and environmental policies have given rise to numerous large investor-state dispute settlement (“ISDS”) claims by E.U. investors. The E.U. has recently ramped up its policy interventions on climate change as part of its Green Deal; new initiatives include mandatory emissions reduction targets, stricter environmental regulations, and subsidies for renewable energy.  The E.U. and its member states want to ensure that the Deal is not derailed by ISDS claims. In other words, the elimination of such claims will prevent regulatory chill that could hamper the carbon neutrality targets set by the bloc.

This leads to the second main argument for an exit: after the Achmea and Komstroy judgements from the Court of Justice of the European Union, and the decisions of several E.U. domestic courts, any new intra-E.U. claims would now be incompatible with E.U. law. Despite these proclamations, all but one arbitral tribunal have rejected all jurisdictional objections based on the various intra-E.U. allegations. Investors simply enforce their intra-E.U. awards in other jurisdictions. Indeed, investors have traditionally had no issue in resorting to U.S. courts to enforce intra-E.U. claims, aside from one recent and heavily criticized exception, and have also enforced awards in the U.K. and Australia. With the coordinated exit, the E.U. and its member states want to ensure that no new claims will be made.

The last argument in favor of the coordinated exit is the desire to avoid claims from carbon-intense industries. Even if these claims fail at the merits stage, they have significant costs. The costs of the proceedings have frequently angered E.U. member states.

III. Much Ado About Nothing?

However, the real question lies in whether the coordinated exit can in fact achieve these three objectives.

A. Application of the Coordinated Exit in the Intra-E.U. regime: Uncertainty Remains

The legal effects of the coordinated exit are twofold. First, the exit will be considered an inter se modification of the ECT under Article 41 of the Vienna Convention on the Law Treaties (“VCLT”) with regards to the ECT sunset clause. Second, the exit will be considered a withdrawal from the ECT (in light of VCLT Article 54 and ECT Article 47) for the rest of the ECT’s provisions. The second effect is not contested. By contrast, the effects of an inter se modification to the sunset clause have stirred substantial debate.

The first legal question is whether the inter se modification would be in accordance with Article 41 of the VCLT. Article 41 introduces two requirements:

  • The modification should “not affect the enjoyment by the other parties of their rights under the treaty or the performance of their obligations” (VCLT Article 41(b)(i));
  • The modification should “not relate to a provision, derogation from which is incompatible with the effective execution of the object and purpose of the treaty as a whole” (VCLT Article 41(b)(ii)).

Academic discourse on whether the inter se modification would meet these criteria remains divided.

An additional lingering issue lies in the operation of ECT Article 16. This provision prohibits the conclusion of a subsequent agreement by parties to the ECT concerning the subject matter of investment protection (ECT Part III) and dispute settlement (ECT Part V) that is less favorable for the covered investors than the protections conferred by the ECT. Several investment tribunals have confirmed that an inter se agreement between E.U. member states cannot restrict access to dispute settlement for investors in intra-E.U. cases. However, ECT Article 16 does not apply to sunset clauses: the sunset provision, ECT Article 47, is not situated in Parts III or V of the ECT.

Still, arbitral tribunals have reiterated that ECT Article 16 evinces an intent by the ECT’s parties to preserve the rights of investors and investments to access dispute settlement—a major plank of the Treaty. Therefore, restrictions such as the removal of the sunset clause could be considered “incompatible with the effective execution of the object and purpose” of the ECT, contrary to VCLT Article 41.  It cannot be taken for granted that tribunals will consistently side for or against view. As long as inconsistency will persist, investors will keep bringing claims.

While the coordinated exit is unlikely to prevent investors from pursuing ECT claims in the coming years, legal uncertainty will remain. This is particularly due to the absence of a mandated consistent approach among investment treaty tribunals. In addition, various factors such as the relevance of the law of the seat may play a crucial role in reaching divergent conclusions. For instance, the Green Power v. Spain tribunal, when accepting the intra-E.U. objection, placed considerable importance on the fact that the law of the seat for a Stockholm Chamber of Commerce (“SCC”) arbitration and the applicable law was Swedish law, which recognizes the primacy of E.U. law. To the contrary, ICSID arbitration is ‘delocalized’ (i.e. there is no ‘seat’); thus, the analysis of the Green Power tribunal is not transposable, as demonstrated by a recent decision.

Hence, the inter se modification, at least prima facie, does not ‘remedy’ the dissatisfaction of the E.U. member states with the intra-E.U. claims. Claims will continue to be submitted at the intra-E.U. level, since as previously explained, investment tribunals remain largely unaffected by the Achmea or Komstroy decisions and the coordinated exit will not necessarily nullify the sunset clause. Tribunals are generally not persuaded by the arguments of primacy of E.U. law over the ECT, and tend to dismiss the relevance of E.U. law in establishing jurisdiction— especially in ICSID arbitrations. Even a recent SCC award recently rejected the intra-E.U. objection, despite the respondent’s reliance on Green Power.

The only real disincentive for claims seems to be legal actions taken in the domestic courts of E.U. member states to ensure non-enforcement. However, as previously mentioned, non-E.U. jurisdictions still remain an option for enforcement.

Further, most intra-E.U. claims raised under the ECT were submitted by renewable energy investors and related to governmental incentives granted and then revoked by E.U. member states. Thus, the goal of avoiding intra-E.U. claims does not necessarily go hand in hand with the promotion of decarbonization. It can hardly be argued that providing additional procedural avenues for costly renewable energy investors would interfere with the E.U. Green Deal.

B. The Coordinated Exit does not Stop Extra-E.U. Claims

In case of a coordinated exit, the ECT sunset clause remains in place and effective between the E.U./member states and third parties. Specifically, the coordinated exit will only apply between the E.U. and member states that have signed up for the exit, leaving third parties’ rights and obligations unaffected.

A few authors argue that the sunset clause could be set aside by virtue of a ‘fundamental change of circumstances’ argument. However, the legal standard to invoke this defense is rather high. Article 62 of the VCLT, which sets out the fundamental change of circumstances standard, has been consistently interpreted by international courts and tribunals, including the International Court of Justice (ICJ). The defense requires the cumulative fulfilment of strict conditions. Notably, the change should be ‘fundamental’ to the circumstances that constituted the essential basis of the consent of the parties to be bound by the treaty. Moreover, the change’s impact must drastically transform the scope of the obligations that are still to be performed under the treaty. The ICJ in Gabčíkovo-Nagymaros denied that progress in environmental knowledge and the emergence of new norms in international environmental law constituted a fundamental change of circumstances. Generally, the ICJ has reiterated that the stability of treaty relations requires that Article 62 VCLT be applied only in exceptional cases.

For these reasons, a fundamental change of circumstances defense by the E.U. and its member states before investment treaty tribunals would likely fail. At a minimum, the defense will not yield a consistent outcome. In other words, the goal of reducing the costs related to arbitral proceedings by preventing the filing of new claims will not be met, even if a very genuine and convincing argument can be made with regards to the fundamental change of circumstances.

The power of the ECT sunset clause means that the ECT will continue to protect dirtyinvestments made by third-country investors in the E.U. (and vice versa) for 20 years. Thus, any alleged regulatory chill will continue to occur, especially given the fact that Switzerland and Japan remain parties to the ECT. At the same time, the decision by the U.K. to exit the ECT means that existing U.K. investments in the E.U. will be protected until 2045. Indeed, the 20-year sunset clause will continue to protect existing investments unless the U.K. agrees with the E.U. and its member states to join the coordinated exit, which seems to be a politically difficult decision post-Brexit. Additionally, ISDS mechanisms may see increased use given the World Trade Organization system deadlock, because ISDS provides an effective and enforceable alternative to challenge the E.U.’s trade-restrictive climate measures. Recently, a national court reiterated that extra-E.U. ISDS cases are compatible with E.U. law.

C. Exporting E.U.-Dirty Industries and Losing the ‘Climate Champion’ Role

The rest of the ECT parties will likely be stuck in a treaty that has been considered by think-tanks as ‘climate wrecking’ in the meantime. This outcome is far from positive. Many ECT members, who already lack ambition on climate change, will be regulated by the old ECT. It is hard to see how the ECT parties will agree on a modernization without the pivotal role of the E.U. The European Commission recently admitted how important it would be for the E.U. and its member states not to block the modernization of the ECT.

Non-modernization of the ECT provides incentives for E.U. investors to invest abroad and escape the E.U.’s tight regulatory environment, furthering the carbon leakage the E.U. is desperately trying to avoid with measures like its carbon border adjustment mechanism (“CBAM”). Simultaneously, E.U. investors will likely re-structure their investments through third countries to benefit from investment treaty protection. They could use an intermediate company in another ECT country (such as Switzerland), or even through states that have comprehensive BITs with E.U. member states (like the UAE and Singapore).

Even if the CBAM or other climate change measures ensure that ‘dirty’ investors will not export back to the E.U., these investors will seek other markets. However, climate change is a global negative externality. Even if the E.U. becomes climate-neutral, the issue will persist. In addition, E.U. investors will have an additional incentive to submit their ISDS claims as soon as possible due to the 20-year sunset clause.

In light of these potential developments, it becomes clear that the coordinated exit does not address the concerns of the E.U. in relation to its Green Deal goals and plan for carbon neutrality. There is little evidence that the ECT ever stood in the way of the E.U. and its member states’ more ambitious policies. At the same time, the need for further cooperation on climate matters exists mostly with respect to non-E.U. countries, especially considering new regulations linked with climate change such as CBAM. The E.U. has been trying to build its role as climate champion; however, at the most crucial time, it has elected to exit the discussion. The exit leaves significant fossil fuel extracting countries stuck with the allegedly ‘climate wrecking’ agreement.

Finally, regarding legal uncertainty and arbitral costs, it appears that denouncing the ECT might ironically also remove one of the more familiar tools we have for managing energy transactions—one that states can monitor, comprehend, and modernize, and one that the public can access. Moving away from the ECT and towards, for example, state contracts and concessions—or even worse, state contracts with stabilization clauses, would favour private contractual obligations, that would provide less policy space than the rules set in investment treaties. Indeed, investment contracts are more problematic than international agreements in terms of transparency and bargaining power, as local politics play an even bigger influence over their terms and conclusion.

IV. Conclusion

In my view, the coordinated exit as outlined above fails to address the goal of reducing ISDS cases that could potentially derail the green transition and is akin to burying our heads in the sand. A coordinated exit will not make the ECT’s climate issues disappear. The ripple effects of the E.U.’s exit will probably lead to a stagnation in climate change discussions and policies in many smaller ECT countries. The rise of geostrategic policies including nationalization of critical raw materials supply chains will likely require the return of the traditional investment law protections that are taken as given. Major oil-producing countries that previously demonstrated active interest in joining the modernized ECT, such as Nigeria, have lost interest after the E.U. announced its plans to exit. A better option would be for the E.U. to push for a more favorable ECT, even with fewer countries. The modernized ECT should include enforceable climate change obligations, exclude intra-E.U. claims, and introduce new procedural rules (e.g., security for costs to avoid frivolous claims) and modernized substantive obligations.

A modernized ECT could ensure a ‘reverse regulatory chill’: it could ensure support towards decarbonization which will not wither or change easily due to changes in the political landscape. States would not renege on the treaty’s climate change commitments without exposing themselves to arbitration proceedings. Ahead of the 2024 elections, the potential rise to power of climate change skeptic politicians in many countries constitutes a significant source of uncertainty on green transition plans. Binding legal provisions can ensure legal stability and predictability that is a conditio sine qua non for investments investment in green technologies and industries.

The various proposals by climate think-tanks presume that states will cooperate and agree on financing and capacity-building mechanisms. As many elections since the mid-2010s have demonstrated, a country’s support towards climate neutrality cannot be taken for granted. At the same time, the need for consensus for any change incentivizes any capital-exporting country to never denounce ECT in order to ensure that its investors have the capacity to sue.

What comes next? We have to wait for the sequel!


Marios Tokas* is a Teaching Assistant and PhD Candidate at the Geneva Graduate Institute (marios.tokas@graduateinstitute.ch). He would like to thank Michail Dekastros and Natalia Mouzoula for their comments and constant support, as well as the HILJ editorial team for their comments.


Cover image credit

Brushing Legal Boundaries: About the Intersection of Law and Art in a Candid Interview with Professor Bullard

Brushing Legal Boundaries: About the Intersection of Law and Art in a Candid Interview with Professor Bullard

Editors’ Note: As part of the HILJ-HIALSA Collaboration on International Arbitration, HIALSA staff interviewed a series of eminent international arbitration practitioners about their experiences in the field and their approaches to international law. The following interview with Professor Alfredo Bullard is the first in this collection. 

“Art, in various forms, contributes significantly to a lawyer’s life. It enhances performance, encourages creative thinking, and, most importantly, allows for a deeper connection with the narratives inherent in legal cases. It helps us to be much better lawyers.”

Professor Bullard

*Professor Alfredo Bullard is the founding partner of Bullard Falla Ezcurra+ (2000) and the partner in charge of the Madrid office. He is a member of the Court of the London Court of International Arbitration and a former member of the International Chamber of Commerce Court of Arbitration. Professor Bullard has appeared as either arbitrator, counsel, or legal expert in more than 300 international arbitrations, and was President of the commission that drafted the Peruvian Arbitration Law. He is also a Professor of Law at Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú and has written and taught on issues in international arbitration around the world. Professor Bullard holds a law degree from Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú and a LL.M. from Yale Law School. 

HIALSA: Let’s begin by exploring your professional journey into law. How did you become passionate about law? Were there specific mentors who played a pivotal role in shaping your career?

Prof. Bullard: Law wasn’t my initial passion. When I encountered law in vocational tests, I emphatically declared that it was the last thing I’d pursue. My initial aspiration was to study literature and to become a writer. It was my father who, with pragmatic wisdom, convinced me that writers don’t necessarily study literature and that becoming a lawyer will allow me to traverse diverse domains. As I delved into law, my initial perceptions transformed. The rigid formality I once perceived gave way to an appreciation for its interdisciplinary facets and its ability to connect various disciplines. 

HIALSA: Transitioning to arbitration, how did your interest in this field unfold?

Prof. Bullard: It’s a story similar to the one that explains why I became a lawyer. Initially, arbitration didn’t capture my interest. In fact, during my law studies, it seemed nonexistent, almost like science fiction. My perspective underwent a significant shift thanks to my colleague, Fernando Cantuarias. He pursued his LL.M. at Yale before me and strongly recommended that I take Professor Michael Reisman’s class on International Arbitration. Despite not listening to his suggestion, I became passionate about arbitration after witnessing Professor Cantuarias’ unwavering dedication to the field. I collaborated with him on Peru’s second Arbitration Law and took advantage of some of the things he knew. As I delved into it, I discovered that I enjoyed arbitration because it allowed me to understand the practical problems behind each case and to delve into other areas of law. Consequently, in the realm of arbitration, I assumed roles as both a litigant and an arbitrator.

HIALSA: You have a diverse professional and academic background as a professor, lawyer, and arbitrator. Do you find one role more personally fulfilling than the others? 

Prof. Bullard: All of these roles mutually enrich each other, offering unique perspectives. If compelled to choose, my preference would lean towards my role as a professor. Teaching is not just a professional endeavor for me; it is a natural calling. Our firm has a distinctive approach, seamlessly integrating academic activities into our professional practices. This commitment involves turning academic endeavors into professionally viable ventures. I firmly believe that teaching is a reciprocal process, imparting knowledge to students while enhancing my own understanding of legal concepts.

HIALSA: At the end of 2022, Bullard Falla Ezcurra + opened its offices in Madrid. Could you share insights into the journey, and your vision for the future of the firm?

Prof. Bullard: The decision to establish our own law firm was driven by a desire to break away from the conventional firm structure. While my previous experiences in other firms provided valuable lessons, I was attracted to a model that allowed for greater flexibility and innovation. The journey involved navigating challenges associated with unconventional approaches in a field often characterized by rigidity.

Our firm offers distinctive interdisciplinary approaches, with a mission centered around creating a professional environment that seamlessly integrates scholarly pursuits. We have consciously invested in initiatives that some firms might deem unconventional, such as staging plays or writing books. The goal is to transform the legal profession into more than just a career but also a source of fulfillment and happiness for our team.

Looking to the future, we anticipate our firm’s continued growth and international presence, providing services that compete with those offered by international firms. This vision led us to establish a presence in Madrid, competing in a more open market with clients not necessarily tied to Peru or Spain. We position ourselves as smaller competitors to large North American or European firms, offering advantages such as our emphasis on interdisciplinary approaches.

HIALSA: We have heard of your passion for travel and theater. How do these personal passions contribute to both your personal and professional life?

Prof. Bullard: Traveling is more than a leisure activity for me; it serves as a source of diverse perspectives that enrich both personal and professional aspects. My recent visit to Africa not only altered my perception of nature but also challenged preconceived notions. Similarly, travel experiences in Singapore and Cambodia left a lasting impact. Living in Europe has further provided an immersive experience in rich cultural diversity. Thus, exposing myself to different legal systems and cultures during my travels has been invaluable and has complimented my work with a deep appreciation for diverse perspectives. 

In my professional life, integrating art, particularly theater techniques, into legal education has been particularly rewarding. For instance, I collaborate with theater directors while preparing my students for arbitration moot court competitions. Law has also allowed me to write plays, such as “El Monstruo de Armendariz,” a play about a murder case and “La Apelación de Shylock”, a continuation of “The Merchant of Venice,” co-written with Professor Giovanni Priori. Currently, I’m working on another play called “El Señor de los Milagros” based on a real trial. 

I truly believe that art, in various forms, contributes significantly to a lawyer’s life. It enhances performance, encourages creative thinking, and, most importantly, allows for a deeper connection with the narratives inherent in legal cases. It helps us to be much better lawyers. 

HIALSA: In your view, what are the most pressing challenges currently facing lawyers and the legal profession? 

Prof. Bullard: I believe a technological revolution is imminent, and only a select few lawyers will navigate it successfully. The world is changing rapidly, prompting a critical examination and swift modification of the decision-making processes.

It’s not just a question of whether advancements like artificial intelligence, new technologies, communication methods, or data processing systems will entail substantial change. Instead, I see it as a paradigm shift. As I discussed in a recent conference, we’re not merely asking if artificial intelligence will replace arbitrators; it will redefine the work we traditionally did through arbitration. The resolution of disputes will take a different form and adapting to this change will be a significant challenge.

HIALSA: Do you have any important advice for students starting law school or those pursuing graduate-level studies in law?

Prof. Bullard: Approach the study of law by maintaining a certain separation from it. While lawyers often develop a profound attachment to the law, it’s crucial to recognize its relativity and evolving nature. The essence of a proficient lawyer lies not only in their knowledge of the law but in understanding that law is a system regulating behaviors, with different competing rules. A skilled lawyer excels in reading, explaining, and understanding the law to achieve broader objectives—ensuring justice, making their client successful, and more.

A notable example is arbitration, the fastest-growing dispute resolution system. Its detachment from strict legal norms is evident in a study by the ICC, revealing that only 33% of awards issued under ICC rules cited relevant applicable law. In 70% of cases, the focus was on interpreting the contract itself. This shift underscores the importance of understanding contracts, which appears to be more crucial than a deep knowledge of the governing law.

HIALSA: If you had to identify an essential characteristic of a good lawyer, what would it be?

Prof. Bullard: Empathy. This characteristic emerges as a fundamental pillar for a lawyer and is rarely found in legal professionals. Understanding different perspectives is essential to achieve persuasion and make narratives relatable. Being empathetic with the other party contributes to increased persuasiveness because the court understands that you are trying to collaborate and contribute to resolving the dispute.

Empathy operates at every level—whether as a boss, witness, expert witness, lawyer, litigator, or arbitrator. Placing oneself in the other’s shoes makes a lot of sense because the essence of the law is nothing else than regulating human conduct.


Cover image credit